Summary
The bigger a firm is, the more efficient. Therefore, bigger and fewer firms in the market should mean lower prices and more goods produced. However, as we can see everyday, this is not really the case. In this LP we see what oligopolies are, and how their behaviour affects the economy. We also see what different types of duopolies there are, and which ones are best suited to analyse this kind of market structure.Basic definitions:
Types of duopolies:
- Cournot duopoly
- Stackelberg duopoly
- Bertrand duopoly
- Edgeworth duopoly
Cournot duopoly, also called Cournot competition, is a model of imperfect competition in which two firms with identical cost functions compete with homogeneous products in a static setting. It was developed by Antoine A. Cournot in his “Researches Into the Mathematical principles of the Theory of Wealth”, 1838. Cournot’s duopoly represented the creation of the study of oligopolies, more particularly duopolies, and expanded the analysis of market structures which, until then, had concentrated on the extremes: perfect competition and monopolies.
Cournot really invented the concept of game theory almost 100 years before John Nash, when he looked at the case of how businesses might behave in a duopoly. There are two firms operating in a limited market. Market production is: P(Q)=a-bQ, where Q=q1+q2 for two firms. Both companies will receive profits derived from a simultaneous decision made by both on how much to produce, and also based on their cost functions: TCi=C-qi.
So, algebraically:
In order to maximise, the first order condition will be:
And, if qi=qj, then both equal:
Therefore, the reaction functions (blue lines), where the key variable is the quantity set by the other firm, will take the following form:
What all this explains is a very basic principle. Both companies are vying for maximum benefits. These benefits are derived from both maximum sales volume (a larger share of the market) and higher prices (higher profitability). The problem stems from the fact that increasing profitability through higher prices can damage revenue by losing market share. What Cournot’s approach does is maximise both market share and profitability by defining optimum prices. This price will be the same for both companies, as otherwise the one with the lower price will obtain full market share, which makes this a Nash equilibrium, also known for this model the Cournot-Nash equilibrium.
If we consider isoprofit curves (those which show the combinations of quantities that will render the same profit to the firm, red curves) we can see that the equilibrium of the game is not Pareto efficient, since isoprofit curves are not tangent. The outcome is below that of perfect competition and therefore is not socially optimal, but it is better than the monopoly outcome.
Extending the model to more than two firms, we can observe that the equilibrium of the game gets closer to the perfect competition outcome as the number of firms increases, decreasing market concentration.
Comparison with Stackelberg duopolies:
-Cournot’s model is a simultaneous game, Stackelberg’s is a sequential game;
-In Cournot duopolies quantity sold is the same for both firms, while in Stackelberg duopolies, the quantity sold by the leader is greater than the quantity sold by the follower;
-When comparing each firm’s output and prices, we have:
Leader: qS1 > qC1 and πS1 > πC1
Follower: qS2 < qC2 and πS2 < πC2
-With regard to total output and prices we have the following:
QM < QC < QS < QPC
PM > PC > PS > PPC = MC
with:
QC: total Cournot output
QS: total Stackelberg output
QPC: total perfect competition output
QM: total monopoly output
PC: Cournot price
PS: Stackelberg price
PPC: perfect competition price
PM: monopoly price
MC: marginal cost