Summary
In this LP we learn about cost efficiency, how to reduce costs while maintaining volume and quality. After understanding how cost efficiency can be achieved, we turn to the main critiques of neoclassical cost analysis. Up to now, everything sounded just as what they’ve been teaching us at school and college. However, a few theories stood up against all this, mainly form Industrial Organization theory.Achieving cost efficiency:
- Economies of scale
- Economies of scope
- Economies of learning
- Learning curve
- Experience curve
Critiques to neoclassical theories:
The concept of economy of scope is very similar to that of economies of scale. When we talk about economies of scope, we mean that average costs are reduced by introducing another product into our portfolio that can share some of the infrastructure or know-how, thus reducing overall average cost per product. It is essentially the same concept as economies of scale, but based on producing more than one product instead of producing more of the same one.
This can happen for various reasons. Firstly, because fixed costs do not increase proportionally with production but rather in stages, we can introduce a second production line that benefits from the common infrastructure whilst reducing average cost per unit.
We can also see a reduction in average variable costs. Employees can benefit from shared know how or from a certain skill set that can be transferred to a much wider range of products, raising productivity across the board. In this way, labour need not increase proportionally with production output, as it is the case for economies of scale. What we can also see here are skills being transferred from one production range to another, resulting in synergies that are unique to economies of scope instead of economies of scale.
In the adjacent figure we see the case of two multi-product firms. The fact that the lower production possibility frontier (PPF) is concave rather than a straight line means that firm B will enjoy economies of scope, and be able to produce two goods for a lower average cost than when producing only one. Therefore, economies of scope exist if, for two goods, we have:
C(x1,x2) < C(x1,0) + C(0,x2)